01 Pages : 1-8
Abstract
This work scrutinises the British struggle for the 1832 ‘Great’ Reform Act by exploring its ups and downs. It, in fact, aims at showing that that Reform Act does not deserve the qualifier ‘Great’ put in inverted commas. Through the historical perspective, the findings have revealed that the 1832 Reform Act took much time to be recognised and passed by Parliament, because political leaders at that time were tyrants and hated all sorts of change. In the long run of time, the bill was then adopted and became law under the masses’ pressure and upheaval. However, after its passage, the political system was slightly changed and the idea of democracy in Britain was, indeed, still a mere masquerade. There were no salaries of MPs, no secret ballot, no regular parliaments, no vote for women, no abolition of property qualification and no constituencies of the same size. It is evident that this appellation is but window dressing. So, this historical misconception should be reviewed and corrected.
Key Words
Struggle, the 1832 ‘Great’ Reform Act, Tyranny,
Democracy
Introduction
Also known as the First Reform Act
or the Representation of the People Act, the British 1832 ‘Great’ Reform Act
was an Act of Parliament of the United Kingdom that introduced major changes to
the electoral system of England and Wales. Between other things, the Act
introduced the first explicit statutory bar to women voting by defining a voter
as a male person, only qualifying men were able to vote, which was already a
problem. Also, the House of Commons of the Unreformed Parliament was composed
of two representative communities namely the counties and the boroughs. Before
1832, there was a big difference between these communities in terms of
representativity. In this respect, Veitch (1965, pp.1-2) wrote:
In the
eighteenth century the representation was already disproportionate. It was the
product, not of plan or principle, but of growth, of custom, even of caprice.
It was, therefore, unequal and inequitable; borough was favoured as against
county, one district as against another; and, to adopt the phrase of modern
politicians, the time was ripe for a distribution of seats.
Moreover, the
right to vote in undemocratic Britain was subject to hard conditions. So,
voting was not a right but a godly privilege given to the wealthier only. By
the way, Pearce and Stearn (2000, p.11) state: “Like everything else in the unreformed
political system, the ability to vote in parliamentary elections was determined
largely by a number of different long-established local conditions. It was not
a right accorded to individuals based on a coherent nationwide system.”
Elections were
an actual battlefield where only the strong and rich people could win the
votes. Violences, corruption, quarrels, and imprisonment of opponents’ fans
sometimes were the relevant instruments used by candidates in order to
intimidate voters to vote in favour of each one of them. When it came to vote,
electors fulfilled their duty publicly. Bribery and corruption were legitimate
during elections. Money was a powerful means through which candidates won
easily the elections. So, this means that the contests were costly affairs. In
fact, these aforementioned facts were the most relevant issues which led to the
passing of the First Reform Act. Thirsty for the betterment of the political
kingdom, radical intellectuals with the help of the common people decided to
attack the government’s leaders who believed in ‘Divine Right of Ruling’. Given
that the latter hated change, they took severe and repressive measures to
intimidate them. These measures plunged the government into a complex conflict
with the population.
The Act took
much time to be passed, and it met most of the time opposition in the House of
Lords. The reason is that aristocratic leaders always wanted the inhabitants to
remain under their control in order to manipulate them. However, as time went
on, Parliament approved the Reform Bill under the masses’ upheaval and became
law. It, in fact, drastically changed the electoral system for the first time,
but left plenty of anomalies at work which necessitated to be cleansed.
Therefore, the foregoing indications result in ‘‘A Critical Analysis of the Ups
and Downs of the British 1832 ‘Great’ Reform Act.’’ This work thus aims to show
that the 1832 Reform Act does not deserve the title of ‘Great Reform Act’.
Numerous studies
exist somehow on this topic. Aidt and Franck (2015) examine the causal effect
of the threat of revolution on democratic change by exploring the impact of
plausibly exogenous variation in threat perceptions on constituency level
support for democratisation in the context of the Great Reform Act in 1832. Aidt and Franck (2008) also suggest a new approach to the study of franchise
extension. They investigate the underlying causes of democratisation by
studying the votes of the politicians who adopt suffrage reforms. Pearce (2003) provides a
vivid and dramatic account of the gruelling parliamentary struggle to pass a
radical reform act in Britain at a time of extreme political frustration and
social unrest. Evans (1994) emphasises the travails of Toryism at the end of the
1820s, complex questions of policy, the connections between the Reform Act of
1832 and subsequent radical activity and reform legislation and presents
revised electoral statistics. Brock (1973) examines the 1832 Reform Act from its struggle to its
passage, including the radicals’ failure.
Grounded on these previous works, this research seeks to answer the following question: can the Reform Act of 1832 actually be hailed as the Great Reform Act? It is supposed that after the adoption of this Act, the idea of democracy in Britain was still a mere illusion. Things would have, however, been worse than pre-1832 period. So, tyranny and anarchy would have taken a new code of ethics and strengthened themselves. To achieve its objective, this analysis is focused on the historical perspective, and a particular emphasis is put on the struggle made before the Act’s passage, its passage, its merits and weaknesses.
Attempts Made Before the Passing of the Act
This section
aims at showing the way the British proceeded so that the Bill of the First
Reform Act could be accepted and given Royal Assent. It is subdivided as
follows: Early Attempts at Reform before the French Revolution, Attempts at
Reform after the French Revolution and Reform in the1820s and in the Start of
1830s.
Early Attempts at Reform before the French Revolution
In the beginning of the struggle for
Parliamentary Reform, English radicals detested theories; and had only a strong
desire for rapid change forgetting that change does not come automatically, but
step by step with time. To sustain this view, Veitch (1965, p.43) asserts:
English parliamentary
reformers had not, as rule, much taste for spinning theories of the State. They
were practical men, impatient of theory, who were seeking practicable solutions
for definite problems, and were groping about for the readiest satisfactory
means of mending the existing Constitution at the points where they found it
most defective.
Furthermore, for Molesworth (1972, pp.4-6), the abuses of which the reformers
complained had existed many centuries earlier. It is evident that many of them
were probably as old as the representative system which expanded in ages when
anarchy and oppression coexisted. If some of these anomalies were occasionally
abolished, but others remained there. Under the reign of Charles I, these
anomalies became hugely visible that they attracted the attention of the Long
Parliament, and decided to increase the number of members returned by the
counties; and the metropolis gave representatives to Manchester, Leeds, and
Halifax; disfranchised an important number of decayed boroughs, and conferred
the elective franchise on every owner of land whatever might be his tenure. In
the same way, it was enacted that representatives should be sent to the House
of Commons from Scotland and Ireland, which was thought fair. Unfortunately,
the civil war was presented as a real obstacle to the implementation of the
proposed changes, but this proposal was later adopted by Oliver Cromwell in
summoning the Parliament of 1645. Hereupon, we can judge this important passage
by saying that the proposal made to redress the prevailing disparities in the
distribution of seats was cordially approved.
Attempts at Reform after the French Revolution
The American and French Revolutions
including the celebration of the hundredth anniversary of the Glorious
Revolution in 1788 had positive and negative impacts on British politics. Here,
we will comment a bit more on the French Revolution of 1789. Indeed,
positively, it gave a real and powerful impetus to the movement of
Parliamentary Reform. It brought inspiration to the friends of reform, both old
and new. It is said in the previous lines of this section that English
reformers were practical men, but the revolution led them to focus more and
more their claims for reform on abstract right and justice. They were now more
interested in justice than convenience.
Negatively, it
again strengthened the opposition’s camp to resist by all possible means the
question of reform. Opponents of reform considered this revolution as a monster
willing to rob their natural power which was established by God himself. But,
here, we are going to focus more on the positive effect of this revolution to
show how it helped the British to move forward with the reform movement despite
any resistance they met. In this light, Andrews (1927) maintained, “(…) the outbreak of the French
Revolution was regarded by the liberals of England as an attempt to eradicate
abuses and secure a more representative government. They greeted it with
outspoken approval (…)”
In the same
way, the revolution led Pitt, quoted by Veitch (1965, p.111), to make the following crucial observation:
The French
Revolution produced a great change. It induced men to look beyond mere party
squabbles. It taught them to despise the jugglery of parties…. The numbers,
too, which now began to think for themselves in respect to government was
increased. Many now saw, or thought they saw, information was necessary to
produce good government. They comprehended their own ignorance and they sought
for information.
Therefore, we understand that the French Revolution was a radical
movement which seriously galvanized the people of Britain to renew the question
of reform with an immense pleasure and a stirring spirit until its
implementation.
Reform in the 1820s and in the Start Of 1830s
As it can be noticed, until this
level, motions which had been presented to Parliament to correct the flaws of
the political system, to make it fair and diminish the distresses and
sufferings of the people were all rejected by considerable majorities of
anti-reformers. Nevertheless, the fact that the government still refused to
approve these motions did not deter the reformers to continue their journey.
This leads Evans (1994, p38) to write:
(…) the Whigs
Lambton and Russell both introduced reform bills in 1821 and 1822. Lambton
called for parliaments to be elected at least once every three years and for a
householder franchise in broadly equal electoral districts. Russell (…)
proposed disfranchising 100 small boroughs and transferring the seats to the
largest towns and the counties. It was no coincidence that internal party
calculations had revealed the smaller boroughs to be disproportionately held by
government supporters! Though Russell was defeated by more than 100 votes (…)
Woodward (1962, p.76) argues
that in 1828, Huskisson and his friends suggested the abolishment of the
corrupt boroughs of East Retford and Penryn so that their seats should be
transferred to unenfranchised towns. He adds that after a discussion:
A compromise
was arranged: East Retford was to be dissolved into the county, and the
representation of Penryn was to be transferred to Manchester. The house of
lords refused to create a new seat for Manchester; Huskisson then declared
himself free to reject the proposal about East Retford. In May 1828 he voted
against the government, and offered to resign.
In February and
May 1830, Russell proposed the enfranchisement of Leeds, Manchester, and
Birmingham, and the removal of the sixty smallest boroughs. But all the
proposals were rejected. Mason (2015, p.25) states:
(…) in February
Lord John Russell tried to give direct representation to Leeds, Manchester and
Birmingham. This was defeated by 188 to 140. In May he tried to take sixty
seats from the smallest boroughs and give them to the counties and the biggest
towns. This failed by 201 votes to 117.
Molesworth (1972, pp.49-50) clarified that on 18th February 1830, the
Marquis of Blandford took the first opportunity of renewing his attempt by
bringing forward a measure of Parliamentary Reform in accordance with the
indications of his rejected motion. It was entitled ‘‘A bill to regulate abuses
in the elections of members of parliament’’, and it was set to restore the
fundamental principles of representation which had been established under the
reign of Henry III and the three Edwards. Those previous battles arguably
resulted centuries later in the passing of the 1832 Reform Act said to be
‘Great.’
The Passing of the Act and Its Ups
To begin with, it is obvious to hold
that the supporters of Parliamentary Reform were not discouraged even after
meeting obstacles in their struggle for reforming Parliament. In fact, Mayer (1999, p.39) asserts that in 1830, George IV who had
resisted the Catholic emancipation and Parliamentary Reform died, and his
brother William IV succeeded him to the throne. The accession of the latter
necessitated a general election during which many people across the country
spoke in favour of reform. This election coincided with significant
advancements in France where a peaceful constitution revolution had taken place
(July Revolution), stating that political change could not happen without
violence. Nevertheless, it abolished tiny districts, gave representation to
cities, gave the vote to small landowners, tenant farmers, shopkeepers,
householders who paid a yearly rental of £10 or more, and some lodgers.
The First
Reform Act was a response of many years battle to the British electoral system.
Indeed, through Mayoke’s analysis (2002, p.32), we understand that the Act eradicated many
abuses of the old representative system. It abolished some of the rotten and
pocket boroughs without compensation for their owners, and the industrial
capitalist and commercial classes began to have their own representatives. It
also served as a basis on which people could claim further political reforms to
positively change the state of things.
The Tories won
a majority in the election, but the party was not united, and support for the
Prime Minister (the Duke of Wellington) was unimportant. When the Opposition
raised the question of reform in one of the first debates of the year, the duke
delivered a controversial speech concerning the existing system of government.
In fact, he, quoted by Mason (2015, pp.26-27), declared:
(…) I am fully
convinced that the country possesses at the present moment a legislature which
answers all the good purposes of legislation, and this to a greater degree than
any Legislature ever has answered in any country whatever. I will go further
and say, that the legislature and the system of representation possess the full
and entire confidence of the country (…) I am not only not prepared to bring
forward any measure of this nature, but I will at once declare that (…) I shall
always feel it my duty to resist such measures when proposed by others.
We clearly
understand by this quotation that the prime minister had severely manifested
antipathy against the question of reform. These absolutist ideas were extremely
unpopular, even within their party. Conacher (1973, pp.6; 11-16) put that on 15th November these
absolutist views made him lost enough support and led to the defeat of his
government in the House of Commons by a majority of twenty-nine, with some
sixty supposed supporters joining the Opposition. After this defeat, Wellington
immediately resigned and the king directly invited Grey to form a new
government. This new government was especially focused on the question of
Parliamentary Reform, as was attested by the inclusion of Durham and Russell in
the ministry (Russell was initially left outside the Cabinet) as well as Henry
Brougham, a one-time Radical reformer, who became Lord Chancellor.
It is crucial to recall that the new
government was composed of four Canningites or Liberal Tories, including Lords
Palmerston and Melbourne, and one Ultra Tory, the Duke of Richmond, who were
separated from Wellington and prepared to accept a Reform Bill. Lord Grey was
greatly influenced by his Radical son-in-law, Lord Durham, and the latter’s
nomination as president of the Cabinet committee to draft the bill was
extremely necessary. When Lord Grey formed his first Government, his core
vision was to propose a large and efficient measure of Parliamentary Reform.
Then he nominated the committee which was in charge of the framing of the first
draft of the measure. This committee was administered by Lord Durham, Lord John
Russell, Sir James Graham and Lord Duncannon on the Prime Minister’s
instructions.
In January
1831, the Cabinet Committee on Reform wrote a Report. Indeed, this report was
hugely important. It contained in a great number of proposals which aimed at
changing the political system for the better in order to satisfy the
expectations of the people. As we can see, it intended to disfranchise the
boroughs which had fewer than 2,000 inhabitants, decided to eliminate one
member from those which had the population under 4,000 and suggested to extend
the franchise to all householders within the town or borough and parish paying
the house tax estimated at £20 per year.
It also
proposed to give representatives to large and populous towns which had more
than 10,000 inhabitants, but had still unrepresented in Parliament. Counties
which had the population over 150,000 should be given additional members and
divided into districts. The forty shillings franchise had to be abolished and
leaseholders paying £50 per annum including copyholders paying £10 per annum
should be enfranchised. It then suggested to reduce the expenses of elections
by insisting on the enforcement of residence, the registration of votes, the adoption
of secret ballot, the increase of the number of polling booths, the shortening
of the duration of the poll and the division of counties. It finally proposed
that the duration of Parliament (parliamentary elections) should be reduced to
five years.
Machin (2001, pp.16-18)
declares that on 1st March 1831, Lord John Russell presented the bill to the
House of Commons and after a debate it passed its second reading by a majority
of one vote only on 23rd March. On 18th April, General Gascoyne proposed an
amendment in committee which claimed to keep the representation of England and
Wales as it was; was defeated by a majority of eight votes. After this defeat,
Parliament was now dissolved by the king on the recommendation of the ministers.
The election that followed weakened the Tory strength in the House of Commons
and greatly enlarged the government’s majority of about 130.
But outside
Parliament, there was much radicalism claiming to obtain manhood suffrage and
the ballot. When the new Parliament met, ministers introduced a second Reform
Bill thanks to radicals’ support, which passed its second reading by 367 votes
to 231 on 6th July. At the committee stage, however, the famous ultra-Tory
amendment known as the Chandos clause was included by a majority of 84. This
clause extended the county franchise to £50 ‘tenants at will’ (meaning farmers
without leases or without guaranteed occupancy for any period, paying at least
£50 annual rent). The clause was effectively viewed as an extension of the
political influence of landlords or landowners, and the government found it
unfair. But some radical leaders including Henry Hunt and Joseph Hume voted for
it because it at least enfranchised several people.
Apart from these merits, the Reform Act failed to satisfy the British
radicals because several anomalies and abuses of the old system remained at
work, which could be labelled as the downs of the Act.
The Downs of the Act
First notice
has hereby to be given that after the 1832 Act, the representative system was
still not under public scrutiny. The influence of patronage, bribery and
corruption continued. Ilbert (1911, p.50) states, “There was no
finality about the Act (…) It did not put an end to bribery, corruption, or the
exercise of undue influence.” At that time, the British population increased as
evidenced by Whitfield (2001, p.72) who writes, “The number of
adult males who were entitled to vote increased from around 478,000 to over
800,000.” However, although there was an increase in the electorate, imbalances
were still prevalent in the number of voters, especially in boroughs. This
disproportion is evidenced by Cunningham (2001, pp.33-34) in these words:
In
1832 in older boroughs in England with both franchises in operation about 40
per cent of the adult male population had the vote, whereas in the new boroughs
it was about 15 percent. In particular boroughs there could be more extreme
differences: in Birmingham, newly enfranchised, only 11 per cent of adult males
were registered to vote, compared to 88 per cent in Preston.
It
is worth noting that the Act just attempted to centre political activity on
middle-class males because their allies from the working-class remained
voteless. This can be understood that it was the Whigs’ prime mission about
reform to secure their interests in Parliament. Smith, quoted by Mayoke (2002, p.34), explains their mission as follows:
The
Whigs had no intention for giving power to the uncouth and violent masses of
the people. They aimed only to enfranchise respectable and intelligent men ‘who
are most interested in preserving tranquillity, and who know how to preserve
it’. The new voters were to be responsible, middle-class people whose
qualification was the amount they paid in rates or rents.
In
addition to this, the distribution of seats in Parliament was still unfair. Old
Corruption never ceased to be influential as Machin (2001, p.22) puts it:
It
is true that much in the electoral system remained the same after the Acts.
Traditional aristocratic influence, and the deference with which it was
accepted, continued to be a marked feature, especially because many small
boroughs survived and continued to return MPs.
Moreover,
the changes brought about by the Reform Act were not always for the better. It
did not change things as people wished them to be. There was much disorder in
the way elections were held. Money was still powerful in elections’ application
and victory. By the way, Cunningham (2001, p.34) makes a crucial analysis:
(…)
the conduct of elections after the Reform Act closely resembled the pre-reform
era- and where there were changes, they were not always for the better. It was
expensive to become an MP. To be qualified to stand in England and Wales
(though not in Scotland) you needed a landed estate worth £600 per annum for a
county seat and £300 per annum for a borough seat.
With
all these imperfections, even if this Act is called the ‘Great’ by some
historians, there is no doubt that after its passage Britain was still too far
to be a truly democratic country because many of the criteria of democracy were
not yet achieved. Evans (2000, p.26) pinpoints:
It
is easy to list what the so-called ‘Great’ Reform Act did not change: no
shorter parliaments; no secret ballot; no constituencies of the same size; no
payment of MPs who anyway still needed a hefty property qualification before
they could take their seats; certainly no manhood suffrage.
However,
from Cunningham’s analysis (2001, p34.), what is surprising is that
candidates were confronted with hard conditions after 1832. They could not
stand without meeting the official and authorised expenses or costs of
elections. They were in charge of erecting booths and hiring rooms in which the
poll should be held, expenses of the returning officers and clerks, the
administration of oaths, fees to local officials, expenses for people to ensure
the security. Apart from this obligation to fulfil, there were other expenses
which some of them resorting to bribery and corruption.
In
some constituencies, there was an established tradition which, unfortunately
the Reform Act did nothing special to eradicate it. This can be illustrated by
the fact that in Yarmouth there was the custom to pay 2 guineas (£2 2s.) to
each voter. In the 1835 election, there was information that the Tories would
give the usual sum of money to people who trusted them. After the failure of
the two Whig sitting members, 550 Tory voters were rewarded. Trying, in fact,
to eradicate corruption of this kind electorally cost death because this
practice was normal in the sight of political opportunists. Those candidates
who only tried to use their speeches to persuade the audience to vote for them
were drastically defeated. Evidence is from the contest held at Norwich in
1835. When standing for this town, Harbord believed in the issue of purity of
elections and was largely defeated with only few votes in his favour than other
Liberal candidate at Norwich in the first decade after the 1832 Act. He
continues by saying that even if the new enfranchised men in 1832 were not
really interested in bribery, but they were also corrupted because in
constituencies where there was the large majority each elector voted twice and
he (2001, pp.35-36) says:
The
new voters enfranchised in 1832 were less likely than older voters to expect or
to receive a bribe. They were also more likely to vote in a partisan way that
is for one party only. In two-member constituencies (the vast majority) each
voter had two votes. Increasingly they either cast both votes for the
candidates of one party, or, if there was only one candidate for the party they
supported, they would ‘plump’, that is use only one of their votes.
In
this way of doing things, we wonder how can a person vote twice at an election?
This is a serious situation in the sense that at that time there were too many
people who could be allowed to vote, but they were excluded from exercising
their right to vote.
In
the same way, the Reform Act failed to grant the right to vote to the majority
of the working-class people. Mason (2015, p.57) stresses that in London
where some of the better-off artisans qualified to vote under £10- householder
franchise were deliberately excluded due to the abolition of ‘potwalloper’ and
‘scot and lot’ franchises. That is the reason why fewer working-class men could
vote than before. As far as women are concerned, no special attention was paid
to their enfranchisement. It means that they were completely ignored in
society.
After
the Reform Act, elections continued to be held publicly as it is aforementioned
that there was no secret ballot so far, for they resulted in entropy. For more
clarification, Whitfield (2001, p.75) asserts:
(…)
Bribery and corruption at elections not only continued but also became more
visible and, probably, more prevalent. There was no effective limit on election
expenses for candidates and the new voters were every bit as corrupt as their
predecessors. At the 1841 election, votes were sold for £4 at Penryn, £7 at
Sudbury and £15 at Ipswich. Contested elections cost candidates large sums of
money; at Nottingham in 1841 the unsuccessful candidates spent £17,000.
He
keeps on explicating that on top of this, there were
other forms of
influence which remained. The new voters among tenant farmers were threatened
by their landlords unless they voted in conformity with their wishes. Violence
and intimidation were still unavoidable in post-1832 elections. In brief,
patronage was not ended. Evans (1994, p.64) said:
Continuity
after 1832 went much further than the survival of a reduced number of managed
boroughs. Effectively, the same people ruled Britain. Of those elected in
December 1832, between 70 and 80 per cent represented the landed interest; the
largest specific category was that comprising sons of peerage.
This simply means that a kind of dictatorship was
prevailing in Britain in the form of parentocracy, a system in which a child's
education must conform to the wealth and wishes of parents rather than the
abilities and efforts of the pupil. Brown (1990, p/66) suggested this in his
text the 'third wave': education and the ideology of parentocracy. Is Britain a
parentocracy? Published in the British Journal of Sociology in which he
explored whether the British really have a choice in their children’s
schooling. According to the spirit of the era and Evans’s quote, Brown’s
question is positively answered.
Conclusion
This work was
premised on the assessment of the British 1832 Reform Act as the ‘Great’ Reform
Act through the exploration of its achievements and failure. In other words,
the question raised was on the recognition of that Act as the Great Reform Act
or not. The results have revealed that the Act took much time to be recognised
and passed by Parliament. The radicals tried many times but their attempts
resulted most of the time in failure. However, these setbacks did not deter
them to continue the struggle. Thanks to their determination and perseverance,
the government yielded and the bill was passed and became law. The Act was
important because it somewhat succeeded in cleansing Parliament for the first
time. It, for example, abolished some pocket and rotten boroughs, increased the
electorate, redistributed seats and put in place a register of electors in each
constituency and gave birth to a long-term democratic battle. Despite the
passage of the bill, the majority of the people remained without the vote, especially
women. Many democratic criteria were still to be met. Through this historical
approach, we are inclined to state that the 1832 Reform Act does not resemble
the appellation of the Great Reform Act. When it was passed, democracy in
Britain was merely a masquerade. It basically gave the vote to middle class
men, leaving working men disappointed. So, this historical misconception should
be reviewed and corrected.
References
- Aidt, T. S., & Franck, R. (2008). “How to Get the Snowball Rolling and Extend the Franchise: https://doi.org/10.17863/CAM.5311
- Voting on the Great Reform of (1832).†Cambridge Working Papers in Economics, Faculty of Economics, University of Cambridge. Available at Pdfdrive.com
- Aidt, T. S., & Franck, R. (2015). “Democratization under the threat of revolution: Evidence from the Great Reform Act of 1832.†Cambridge Working Papers in Economics, Faculty of Economics, University of Cambridge. https://www.jstor.org/stable/43616944
- Andrews, G. G. (1927). Parliamentary Reform in England 1830-1832. New York: FS. Crofts & Co
- Brock, M. (1973). The Great Reform Act. London: Hutchinson.
- Conacher, J. B. (1973). The Emergence of British Parliamentary Democracy in the Nineteenth Century: The Passing of the Reform Acts of 1832, 1867, and 1884-1885. New York: Wiley
- Cunningham, H. (2001). The Challenge of Democracy: 1832-1918. Harlow: Longman.
- Evans, E. J. (2000) . Parliamentary Reform, c. 1770Ë— 1918. Harlow: Longman.
- Evans, E. J. (1994). The Great Reform Act of 1832 (2nd Ed). London: Routledge
- Ilbert, C. (1911). Parliament: Its History, Constitution and Practice. New York: Henry Holt and Company.
- Machin, I. (2001). The Rise of Democracy in Britain, 1830Ë— 1918. Basingstoke: MacMillan.
- Mason, R. (2015). The Struggle for Democracy: Parliamentary Reform, from Rotten Boroughs to Today. Brimscombe Port: The History Press.
- Mayer, A. (1999). The Growth of Democracy in Britain. London: Hodder & Stoughton
- Mayoke, A. G. (2002). “The British People’s Fight for Electoral Freedom in the Nineteenth and Twentieth Centuriesâ€. Marien Ngouabi University, Brazzaville: Master’s thesis.
- Molesworth, W. N. (1972). The History of the Reform Bill of 1832. Clifton: A.M. Kelly.
- Pearce, E. (2003). Reform! The Fight for the 1832 Reform Act. London: Jonathan Cape
- Pearce, R., & Stearn, R. (2000). Government and Reform: Britain 1815Ë— 1918 (2nd Ed). London: Hodder & Sloughton
- Veitch, G. S. (1965). The Genesis of Parliamentary Reform. London: Constable.
- Whitfield, Bob. (2001). The Extension of the Franchise, 1832Ë— 1931. Harlow: Heinemann
- Woodward, L. (1962). The Age of Reform 1815Ë— 1870 (2nd Ed). New York: Oxford University Press.
- Aidt, T. S., & Franck, R. (2008). “How to Get the Snowball Rolling and Extend the Franchise: https://doi.org/10.17863/CAM.5311
- Voting on the Great Reform of (1832).†Cambridge Working Papers in Economics, Faculty of Economics, University of Cambridge. Available at Pdfdrive.com
- Aidt, T. S., & Franck, R. (2015). “Democratization under the threat of revolution: Evidence from the Great Reform Act of 1832.†Cambridge Working Papers in Economics, Faculty of Economics, University of Cambridge. https://www.jstor.org/stable/43616944
- Andrews, G. G. (1927). Parliamentary Reform in England 1830-1832. New York: FS. Crofts & Co
- Brock, M. (1973). The Great Reform Act. London: Hutchinson.
- Conacher, J. B. (1973). The Emergence of British Parliamentary Democracy in the Nineteenth Century: The Passing of the Reform Acts of 1832, 1867, and 1884-1885. New York: Wiley
- Cunningham, H. (2001). The Challenge of Democracy: 1832-1918. Harlow: Longman.
- Evans, E. J. (2000) . Parliamentary Reform, c. 1770Ë— 1918. Harlow: Longman.
- Evans, E. J. (1994). The Great Reform Act of 1832 (2nd Ed). London: Routledge
- Ilbert, C. (1911). Parliament: Its History, Constitution and Practice. New York: Henry Holt and Company.
- Machin, I. (2001). The Rise of Democracy in Britain, 1830Ë— 1918. Basingstoke: MacMillan.
- Mason, R. (2015). The Struggle for Democracy: Parliamentary Reform, from Rotten Boroughs to Today. Brimscombe Port: The History Press.
- Mayer, A. (1999). The Growth of Democracy in Britain. London: Hodder & Stoughton
- Mayoke, A. G. (2002). “The British People’s Fight for Electoral Freedom in the Nineteenth and Twentieth Centuriesâ€. Marien Ngouabi University, Brazzaville: Master’s thesis.
- Molesworth, W. N. (1972). The History of the Reform Bill of 1832. Clifton: A.M. Kelly.
- Pearce, E. (2003). Reform! The Fight for the 1832 Reform Act. London: Jonathan Cape
- Pearce, R., & Stearn, R. (2000). Government and Reform: Britain 1815Ë— 1918 (2nd Ed). London: Hodder & Sloughton
- Veitch, G. S. (1965). The Genesis of Parliamentary Reform. London: Constable.
- Whitfield, Bob. (2001). The Extension of the Franchise, 1832Ë— 1931. Harlow: Heinemann
- Woodward, L. (1962). The Age of Reform 1815Ë— 1870 (2nd Ed). New York: Oxford University Press.
Cite this article
-
APA : Ngatsongo, G., Mbon, A., & Loumbouzi, D. A. A. (2023). A Critical Analysis of the Ups and Downs of the British 1832 'Great' Reform Act. Global Legal Studies Review, VIII(III), 1-8. https://doi.org/10.31703/glsr.2023(VIII-III).01
-
CHICAGO : Ngatsongo, Garel, Armel Mbon, and Didier Arcade Ange Loumbouzi. 2023. "A Critical Analysis of the Ups and Downs of the British 1832 'Great' Reform Act." Global Legal Studies Review, VIII (III): 1-8 doi: 10.31703/glsr.2023(VIII-III).01
-
HARVARD : NGATSONGO, G., MBON, A. & LOUMBOUZI, D. A. A. 2023. A Critical Analysis of the Ups and Downs of the British 1832 'Great' Reform Act. Global Legal Studies Review, VIII, 1-8.
-
MHRA : Ngatsongo, Garel, Armel Mbon, and Didier Arcade Ange Loumbouzi. 2023. "A Critical Analysis of the Ups and Downs of the British 1832 'Great' Reform Act." Global Legal Studies Review, VIII: 1-8
-
MLA : Ngatsongo, Garel, Armel Mbon, and Didier Arcade Ange Loumbouzi. "A Critical Analysis of the Ups and Downs of the British 1832 'Great' Reform Act." Global Legal Studies Review, VIII.III (2023): 1-8 Print.
-
OXFORD : Ngatsongo, Garel, Mbon, Armel, and Loumbouzi, Didier Arcade Ange (2023), "A Critical Analysis of the Ups and Downs of the British 1832 'Great' Reform Act", Global Legal Studies Review, VIII (III), 1-8
-
TURABIAN : Ngatsongo, Garel, Armel Mbon, and Didier Arcade Ange Loumbouzi. "A Critical Analysis of the Ups and Downs of the British 1832 'Great' Reform Act." Global Legal Studies Review VIII, no. III (2023): 1-8. https://doi.org/10.31703/glsr.2023(VIII-III).01